# Monetary Primer

The idea of dollar voting or "voting with your wallet" has been a recognized phenomenon for about the past 50 or 75 years. The notion has a great deal of intuitive appeal as well. We work hard for our money, so why wouldn't we want what we spend our money on to align with our values and how we see ourselves?

One could even argue that the community currency movement, those attempts to create currencies specific to local communities, is a philosophical cousin to the idea of dollar voting. Both spring from the idea that money isn't currently but can be aligned with our own values and goals.

Unfortunately, it is not difficult to find major shortcomings in both movements, which we'll jointly refer to as value-based monetary movements. Dollar voting struggles in the face of gross information asymmetry between consumers and producers--greenwashing, pinkwashing, etc. Additionally, nearly all demonstrable benefits from community currency can only be found in those select situations where communities suffer from major swings in seasonal liquidity, as in the case of smallholder farming communities that only have 1 or 2 harvests a year (Zeller, 2020).

# Principles of Sound Money

Conventional wisdom states that there are 3 necessary functions that an asset must perform to be considered good or effective money.

Medium of exchange. The money can be used easily and effectively to realize the exchange of goods and services. Tangibly, for a money to be an effective medium of exchange, a participant must be able to physically or digitally bring the money to a place of commerce (like a store) and have the confidence to reasonably expect that their money will be accepted in exchange for what they wish to purchase.

Unit of account. The function of being a unit of account is arguably related to that of being a medium of exchange. Money used as a unit of account provides common units that can be assigned to the price of different goods and services for the purposes of comparison and evaluation. If a participant is told that Store A has the item they want for 50 #s and Store B is selling it for 46 #s, then #s are a good money only if they can rely upon those two statements to know that Store B is offering the better deal.

Store of value. The most discussed (and most challenging) role for a money is that as a store of value. A good form of money will be able to purchase a constant or near constant basic of goods even over time. The strong form of this requirement is arguably impossible, as baskets of goods and the real cost involved in production change over time, or even not advisable, if one is especially concerned about sticky wages. However, what we'll call the weak form of the requirement, that good money lose its value slowly (<3% a year) and predictably, is broadly agreed upon by economists and (ordinarily) achieved by the world's major central banks.

Beyond these 3 broadly agreed to functions of money, we believe that money ideally has two additional functions that closely relate to both the successes and failures of value-based monetary movements.

# Economic Counterweight

The key feature of economic thought and monetary decision making over the past 75 years is the notion that good money is countercyclical, playing the role of an economic counterweight to prevailing conditions. When an economy is struggling, making money cheaper or easier to obtain, can help boost growth. Conversely, if it looks as though an economy may be ballooning at an unsustainable pace that's likely to pop, then money can be made more expensive and scarcer.

In with fiat money, this function is carried out primarily through the adjustment of interest rates. In the case of community currencies in agricultural areas of the Global South, the increased access to funds during outside of the harvest windfall also acts as a counterweight, providing easier access to money exactly when it is needed to prevent activity from seizing up due to a shortage of liquidity. Because the issue of seasonally restricted liquidity is largely unique to these communities, community currencies (backed by development aid) play a unique countercyclical role that is not present in the experiments carried out in the Global North.

# Collective Subsidy

As conventional monetary policy transitioned from gold to fiat, and the idea of countercyclical currency rose, the concept of seigniorage has become thought of as a artifact. Seigniorage is defined as the difference between the cost of producing a currency and the value for which it can be sold or distributed. A archetypal example of seigniorage emerges when a government issuing gold or silver currency begins mixing in less precious metals but keeps the face value of the coins constant. The cost of producing the currency has been reduced, the value brought in remains the same (at least initially), so seigniorage increases.

Provided the function is not used to excess, the creation of seigniorage is an important role for good money as it can provide a key means for a state to finance its operations. This role can be especially powerful for newer or emerging states that may have more tenuous tax base. If we think beyond the nation state, we can see seigniorage as a means for communities, movements, or network states to bootstrap capital for themselves or in the furtherance of common values.

It is this final prong of good money, the constructive direction of seigniorage that is a far more powerful tool toward a value-based monetary system.